Tuesday 2 April 2013

Pimp My Parliament


On September 14 this year, Australians will elect the 150 members of the House of Representatives, a number unchanged since 2001, and which has only increased by two since 1984, and by twenty-nine since 1949. By contrast, our fellow Westminster democracy across the Pacific will increase the size of its House of Commons from 308 to 338 in time for its next general election, so as to accommodate the rapidly-growing suburban areas of Ontario, British Columbia, and Alberta. On the measure most often used by political scientists to estimate the size of a country’s legislature, the cube root rule, Australia is an outlier in terms of its ratio of population to seats, and our current parliament looks even less adequate when one considers the difficulties of representing super-sized electorates such as Durack, O’Connor, Lingiari, Grey, and Kennedy.

The size of the House is a function of the size of the Senate; the constitution requires that the Representatives from the states be twice as numerous as the Senators from the states, but gives parliament some leeway in determining what formula to use. The size of the Senate, however, is entirely at the mercy of parliamentary legislation, with the proviso that the six Original States must have the same representation and at least six Senators each. On two occasions, preceding the 1949 and 1984 federal elections, parliament has increased the number of Senators per state, causing a commensurate enlargement of the House.

If Australia had the same ratio of MHRs to population as Canada or Britain, it would have between 200 and 250. New Zealand, with one-fifth our population, has 70 electorate MPs and 50 list MPs. If we adopted the sliding scale originally proposed for the United States in Article the First, we would have between 350 and 400. And having a House of 500 or 600 members would align us with Germany, France, and Italy – all nations with three times our population but a much more even spread of people.

The small size of our parliament is harmful to our democracy. It forces parties to focus on a narrow set of marginal seats in order to win office, so that every three years we get saturation coverage of the minute goings-on in Lindsay and Eden-Monaro. The small number of electorates to go around means that some are ridiculously large (remember the pre-2010 Kalgoorlie?) and lacking in community of interest (eg. Albury and Broken Hill being united in Farrer, or the Sydney-Grayndler boundary splitting Balmain from Leichhardt and Newtown from Marrickville). The small size of the House also meant that Australia’s parties couldn’t adopt the British tradition of a non-partisan Speaker. Finally, the constitutional requirement that Tasmania receive five MHRs (when its population currently hovers just over 3.5 quotas), means that the mainland states (and the ACT) are slightly under-represented, a problem which would be accentuated if Australia had states with much smaller populations than Tassie.

My proposal is that Australia imitate one of the best-governed little jurisdictions in the democratic world – New Hampshire – and elect a 400-member lower house; getting there would require an enlargement of the Senate or a constitutional amendment to break the ‘nexus’ clause. The advantages of a 400-member House of Representatives are manifold:

* smaller electorates means cheaper campaigns and more chances of winning seats for independents and minor parties whose support is geographically concentrated (eg. the Greens presently have much more chance of winning the state seat of Brunswick than the federal seat of Wills);
* more parliamentary seats means more nominations to go around for female, young, and racial minority candidates;
* smaller electorates means that geographically-concentrated racial minorities have more chance of dominating particular seats – the current federal division with the highest Aboriginal population is Lingiari (represented by white Labor MP Warren Snowdon) where they form less than two-fifths of the enrolment; with 400 seats, majority- or near-majority Aboriginal seats could be drawn in the Territory, the Kimberley, North Queensland, and north-western NSW;
* a larger House means that front-benchers would make up a smaller percentage of its members, and thus back-benchers could exert more power over their party’s leadership;
* more electorates means that redistribution commissioners would be better able to draw sensible boundaries; federal seats would better reflect the natural socio-cultural regions of our cities and states, rather than random agglomerations of different areas named after obscure historical figures.

Of course, such a proposal will always be unpopular with the general public, among whom arguments about better representation can’t compete with mindless anti-politician populism, and with politicians themselves, who would rather have 1/150th of the federal pie than 1/400th. Still, one can dream…

No comments:

Post a Comment