The top-two runoff is most commonly
associated with French presidential elections (parliamentary and département elections there are also
held over two rounds, but more than two candidates can make the runoff). It was
exported to many French colonies, and in the United
States , it has only been used in Louisiana (fittingly, given its French
heritage). In this post, I will draw from the French and Louisiana
experience to explain why the ‘Top Two’ system is not a good choice for California .
The Le Pen/Duke problem: both France and Louisiana have had a
candidate of the far-right make the runoff in a low-turnout election filled
with multiple candidacies. In Louisiana
in 1991, division among Republicans led Klansman David Duke to clinch a spot in
the gubernatorial runoff against veteran Democratic pol Edwin Edwards. (When
asked if there were any similarities between him and his opponent, Edwards
remarked that “we’re both wizards between the sheets”.) In France in 2002,
no-one in the sixteen-candidate field received more than twenty percent of the
vote, the top three being incumbent Gaullist President Jacques Chirac (19.9%),
National Front leader Jean-Marie Le Pen (16.8%), and incumbent Socialist PM
Lionel Jospin (16.2%). Jospin’s problem was the division among left-wing
candidates – the combined vote of the five parties in his parliamentary coalition
was over thirty percent. (Due to the threat of causing another such electoral
earthquake, two of those parties have never since run presidential candidates.)
Both these elections were walkovers for the mainstream candidate, while an
extremist was given some measure of respectability by appearing beside them in
the runoff. If Orly Taitz’s campaign had picked up more momentum, California could have
witnessed a similar showdown this year.
The ‘Bonnet blanc ou blanc bonnet’
problem: in 1969, thanks to a poor showing by France ’s
left (the Communist candidate ran third and the Socialists, without François
Mitterrand as their standard-bearer, couldn’t get into double digits), the
presidential runoff was contested between two rightist candidates: George
Pompidou of the Gaullist UDR and Alain Poher of the Christian democratic MRP.
In the second round, the Communist candidate, Jacques Duclos, refused to
endorse, declaring the two front-runners to be “bonnet blanc ou blanc bonnet”
(the equivalent English phrase is ‘six of one and half a dozen of the other’).
The result was lower turnout, most markedly in working-class areas where the
Communist Party was strongest. Similarly, Louisiana most recently experienced an
all-Democratic gubernatorial runoff in 1987, but runner-up Edwin Edwards
withdrew in favour of first-round winner Buddy Roemer (who switched parties
during his term). A few Californian races will likely experience something
similar in November: two runoff contenders of the same party leading to low
turnout from supporters of the other, leading in turn to effects on up-ballot
and down-ballot races.
The Chirac/Giscard problem: after seven years in office, Valéry Giscard d’Estaing of the UDF (a
mélange of Christian democrats, classical liberals, and rural conservatives)
was challenged for the leadership of France’s right by Chirac, his former prime
minister, who had resigned in 1976 over fiscal policy differences (he wanted
Keynesianism, Giscard austerity), and spent the next five years
passive-aggressively acting as a quasi-opposition figure, including denouncing
the UDF as the ‘foreign party’ (parti de
l’étranger) for its pro-European policies. In 1981, he jumped into a
four-way contest against Giscard, Mitterrand, and Communist Georges Marchais.
(The four main parties were so evenly poised in terms of vote share that a
repeat of 1969 – a Giscard/Chirac or Mitterrand/Marchais runoff – seemed
possible.) After placing third, Chirac refused to make a full endorsement of
Giscard, saying that he would personally vote for him but wouldn’t recommend
his supporters do so. With three of the last four opinion polls giving a 50-50
tie in the runoff, Chirac’s non-endorsement endorsement certainly made the
difference. Instead of the two-week interval in French presidential polls,
disgruntled Californian politicos have five months to ‘do a Chirac’ on
erstwhile allies who’ve beaten them into the runoff.
The legitimacy problem: when France
held its first direct presidential poll in 1965, Charles de Gaulle and François
Mitterrand were both able to poll above thirty percent in the first round. By
contrast, no-one hit twenty percent in 2002, or thirty percent in 2012.
(Nicholas Sarkozy managed 31.2% in 2007, thanks largely to an absence of other
mainstream right-of-centre candidates.) The fragmentation of the electorate
means that a repeat of 2002 is possible: indeed, polls in 2010 had Le Pen’s
daughter Marine in a virtual three-way tie with Sarkozy and Dominique
Strauss-Kahn. California
will see members of Congress elected this year after having scored less than a
quarter of the first-round vote, an outcome which their opponents will be able
to hold against them for the length of their terms.
The Chirac/Barre/Balladur problem: another consequence of the two-round system is that even when two
candidates from the mainstream left and right face off, their party affiliation
can be uncertain. Giscard or Chirac could have been the right’s runoff
candidate in 1981, and Chirac was almost successfully challenged in 1988 (by
the UDF’s Raymond Barre) and in 1995 (by dissident Gaullist Édouard Balladur).
When the Greens almost overtook the Socialists at the 2009 European elections,
it was conceivable that a similar dynamic might play out on the French left in
2012, but the Green surge was short-lived. California ’s Democrat-GOP duopoly means it
will avoid the inter-party effects of this problem, but this year’s Senate
runoff is reminiscent of French elections. Incumbent Dianne Feinstein was the
overwhelming choice of Democrats (49.5%), but the Republican field was
splintered, and Elizabeth Emken goes into the runoff having obtained only 12.6%
in the first round; Emken now has to win over the supporters of the other
Republican candidates who collectively polled double her vote, while
Feinstein’s fellow Democrats polled one-seventh of her total.
In addition to these criticisms, I will add
a few general negatives of the ‘Top Two’ system as used in California . Firstly, because a candidate
winning a majority of the first-round vote can’t be declared elected yet (a
member of Congress can’t be elected until November, hence why Louisiana was
forced to shift its ‘primary’ to election day and its runoff to December), a
runoff will be held in districts where the candidate has already virtually been
decided. Nancy Pelosi, for example, polled 74.5% in the San Francisco-based
Twelfth District, but faces a Republican challenger in the runoff who received
14%. In some districts, there were only two candidates in the first round, and
the same two will feature in a rather pointless runoff.
Secondly, the multiplicity of candidates
with the same party affiliation makes it harder for voters to determine the
ideological position of each candidate. The major parties are endorsing candidates,
but that information is buried in the back pages of official voter guides.
Political scientists have forever argued that strong parties make for a strong
democracy, but California ’s
system encourages inter-party rivalry and random, uninformed choices. For
example, I don’t believe that two percent of San Franciscans are LaRouchites –
but a LaRouchite candidate running as a Democrat earned two percent of the vote
there; Democrats who wanted to send a message to Nancy Pelosi had three other
candidates to choose from, and little way of knowing that one was an extremist.
Finally, the supporters of the ‘Top Two’
system seem to hope that centrists will be successful by appealing to voters
from both parties – but remember that this electoral system propelled David
Duke and Jean-Marie Le Pen to runoffs. Even if it were true, the usual
suspects, such
as the state’s moderate Republicans, welcome it is a means of diluting the
supposed menace of partisanship. Proposition 14, which won every county in the
state except hyper-Democratic San Francisco and hyper-Republican Orange, was
produced by the same technocratic, anti-political mentality that gave us
Americans Elect, Unity08, and No Labels. The people of California have been sold a panacea for the
state’s political woes which creates more problems than it solves.
The ‘Top Two’ system suffers from the usual
defects of majoritarian systems: the marginalisation of minor parties, the role
of ‘spoiler’ played by a successful one, and the incentive for parties to
choose an inoffensive, moderate candidate (usually white, male, straight,
middle-aged, etc.) For these reasons, I would recommend that every jurisdiction
on Earth adopt some form of proportional representation; failing that, the
Alternative Vote is the best majoritarian method, as it maximises voter choice
and prevents votes from being ‘wasted’. But if California insists on the
two-round system, it might consider the variant used in parliamentary and local
elections in France: the top two qualify for the runoff, plus any others who
poll over a certain threshold (10% or 12.5%). Candidates from the same side of
politics are able to withdraw in favour of the other, making most runoffs a
straight two-way contest: 417
out of 557 parliamentary seats will see a left-right duel in the runoffs
there on June 17.
No comments:
Post a Comment